Monday, October 1, 2018

Youtube daily report Oct 1 2018

SciShow is supported by Brilliant.org.

[ ♪ INTRO ]

Around 74,000 years ago, in what's now Sumatra, a volcano called Toba exploded.

It was the largest known eruption in at least the past two million years,

a whole order of magnitude bigger than the 19th-century eruption of Tambora,

which is the largest volcanic eruption in recorded history.

The Toba eruption produced 2800 cubic kilometers of magma, deposited meters-thick layers of ash,

and spewed thousands of tons of sulfuric acid and sulfur dioxide into the atmosphere.

It may have caused global temperatures to dip by as much as 10 degrees Celsius for the next decade

— with some cooling lasting nearly a thousand years.

This was the Middle Paleolithic Period, when the height of human technology was stone tools and fire.

So you get why scientists would think the giant explosion had a serious impact on the human population.

But the evidence seems to show that humanity was … mostly fine.

And we're not totally sure why.

The main climate effects from volcanoes come from the ash and sulfurous gases they belch out.

After a big eruption, this stuff can circulate in the atmosphere for years, reflecting sunlight

and causing global cooling — hence that possible decade-long volcanic winter caused by Toba.

It makes sense that an endless global winter would be bad news for the planet's inhabitants.

For comparison, the eruption of nearby Tambora turned 1816 into what became known as "the year without a summer"

and led to crop failure and famine around the world.

And Tambora only put out 175 cubic kilometers of stuff, compared to Toba's thousands.

So in the 1990s a scientist named Stanley Ambrose proposed what's been called the Toba catastrophe theory.

His idea was that the eruption might have nearly wiped out humanity,

reducing the global population from around 100,000 people to around 10,000.

People of African ancestry are more genetically diverse than other humans,

which seems to suggest that the rest of humanity experienced a genetic bottleneck at some point

— a dramatic drop in population that resulted in a loss of genetic diversity.

According to the Toba catastrophe theory, the giant volcanic eruption and the global winter that followed were the culprits.

Africans' tropical home, the theory goes, helped buffer them against the effects of the volcanic winter

and prevented the huge population declines that happened in other areas.

Which sounds plausible.

But as we've continued to look for evidence of the so-called Toba catastrophe, things have become a lot less clear.

For one thing, scientists don't all agree on just how bad the eruption's effects on the climate actually were.

In 2010, researchers created a mathematical model of the eruption's possible climate

effects, based on how the particles it shot into the atmosphere would have reflected solar energy.

Their results showed that the eruption's global effects may have been milder and shorter-lived

than originally theorized — like a three to five degree drop in temperature for two or three years,

instead of a ten degree drop that lasted a decade.

That's still a really big deal — a drop of just one degree was enough to cause the year without a summer.

But maybe it wasn't a big enough deal to kill off 90% of the world's population.

Recent research has also found that charcoal and plant particles in sediment samples from Africa's Lake Malawi

don't show any big change in plant life before and after the eruption.

Which is something you'd definitely expect to see if there had been a ten-year-long winter.

And, the more archaeologists look for evidence of what actually happened to humans around this time,

the more it looks like the answer is … nothing too devastating.

A recent study from the coast of South Africa didn't find any interruption in human activity there.

There is a layer of tiny volcanic glass shards from the eruption in archaeological deposits,

but the human artifacts from before and after are pretty much the same.

Some of the researchers involved suggested that living in a warm,

coastal area with lots of resources might have helped people there thrive despite the eruption.

But archaeological studies from much closer to the blast zone in India — don't show

much change in human communities there around the time of the eruption, either.

Humans probably were affected by Toba — the largest volcanic eruption in our history would be hard to ignore.

But the latest evidence makes it seem pretty unlikely that 90% of the global population was killed off,

and today most scientists consider the Toba catastrophe theory to be debunked.

But that still leaves the question of what caused the genetic bottleneck as humans were expanding out of Africa.

The most widely accepted explanation today is that it was a simple case of what's called the founder effect.

Only relatively small groups of humans ever made the trek out of Africa,

limiting the genetic diversity of their descendents as they populated the rest of the world.

Perhaps the closest parallel to Toba threatening the world today is the massive volcano underneath Yellowstone National Park.

One of the Yellowstone supervolcano's past eruptions, around two million years ago, was almost on the scale of Toba,

spewing about 2500 cubic kilometers of magma.

And today, humans rely on way more technology that would be negatively affected than we

did at the time of Toba, from agriculture to airplanes.

In some ways, our society is more fragile than it was back then.

So a modern Yellowstone eruption would be really bad news.

But volcanologists say the chances of Yellowstone blowing up any time soon are incredibly small,

so don't lose too much sleep over it.

Ultimately, though, even an eruption as large as Toba's didn't really alter the course of humanity's genetic history.

Mind-bogglingly huge volcanic eruptions like Toba are a reminder of just how violent our planet's geology can be

— but in this case, it also showed that our species can be pretty resilient.

Go humans!

Thanks to Brilliant.org for sponsoring this episode, and this whole week, of SciShow.

Trying to unpack natural disasters from the past, or make predictions about the future

is a lot more interdisciplinary than we tend to think.

Scientists need to know about geology and weather, and in this case anthropology, but also probability.

All this week we're pointing out fun, interactive courses on Brilliant.org, and one of my favorites is Probability in Science.

This particular quiz starts you out learning about probability from the point of view of

a medical doctor, but soon you're in deep space trying to use probability to disprove aliens.

I mean, it's never been aliens...yet.

You can check out the wide array of courses by going to Brilliant.org/SciShow.

Right now, the first 200 SciShow viewers to sign up will get 20% off of the annual premium subscription.

And let me know how you do on the Probability quiz!

Or if you prove the existence of aliens!

[ ♪ OUTRO ]

For more infomation >> The Biggest Volcanic Eruption in Human History - Duration: 5:46.

-------------------------------------------

"Überstieg alles": Uwe Herrmann über Martina Bigs Kleidsuche - Duration: 2:36.

For more infomation >> "Überstieg alles": Uwe Herrmann über Martina Bigs Kleidsuche - Duration: 2:36.

-------------------------------------------

Lo Maan Liya |Raaz Reboot |Flute & Piano Cover | |Instrumental| 2018 |Ft. Tonmay Chakraborty| - Duration: 2:53.

Lo Maan Liya Flute & Piano Cover

For more infomation >> Lo Maan Liya |Raaz Reboot |Flute & Piano Cover | |Instrumental| 2018 |Ft. Tonmay Chakraborty| - Duration: 2:53.

-------------------------------------------

Opel Astra 5drs 1.0 Turbo 105pk Online Edition | Navi | Climate - Duration: 0:54.

For more infomation >> Opel Astra 5drs 1.0 Turbo 105pk Online Edition | Navi | Climate - Duration: 0:54.

-------------------------------------------

Renault Scénic 1.5 DCI BOSE AUTOMAAT!! Nav/Climate/Half-Leder - Duration: 1:06.

For more infomation >> Renault Scénic 1.5 DCI BOSE AUTOMAAT!! Nav/Climate/Half-Leder - Duration: 1:06.

-------------------------------------------

Seat Leon St 1.4 EcoTSI 150PK FR 18 inch/Navi/Clima - Duration: 1:08.

For more infomation >> Seat Leon St 1.4 EcoTSI 150PK FR 18 inch/Navi/Clima - Duration: 1:08.

-------------------------------------------

La Reina Del Flow - LA CAIDA DEFINITIVA DE CHARLY FLOW - GRAN FINAL 9 DE OCTUBRE 😱 - Duration: 2:25.

For more infomation >> La Reina Del Flow - LA CAIDA DEFINITIVA DE CHARLY FLOW - GRAN FINAL 9 DE OCTUBRE 😱 - Duration: 2:25.

-------------------------------------------

CRYSIS 3 - 20.BÖLÜM NASIL OYNANIR? - Duration: 15:42.

For more infomation >> CRYSIS 3 - 20.BÖLÜM NASIL OYNANIR? - Duration: 15:42.

-------------------------------------------

U.S. Drug Prices: Why Are They So High? - Duration: 1:04:18.

MICHELLE WILLIAMS: Welcome to The Forum,

live-streamed worldwide from the Leadership Studio

at the Harvard T.H. Chan School of Public Health.

I'm Dean Michelle Williams.

The Forum is a collaboration between the Harvard Chan School

and independent news media.

Each program features a panel of experts

addressing some of today's most pressing public health issues.

The Forum is one way the school advances

the frontiers of public health, and makes

scientific insights accessible to policymakers and the public.

I hope you find this program engaging and informative.

Thank you for joining us.

CAROLINE HUMER: Welcome.

My name is Caroline Humer.

I'm a correspondent, I work for Reuters.

And I'm your moderator today.

We're here today to discuss US drug prices.

Why are they so high?

The US spends the most per capita on prescription drugs

compared to other high income countries, according to a 2017,

Commonwealth Fund report.

Companies that astronomically hike prices on some drugs,

such as the infamous 5,000 percent

increase on the antibiotic Daraprim in 2015,

grab headlines.

And some Americans are still struggling

to cope with their medical expenses.

Sometimes they skip their prescriptions altogether,

or they ration it and take less than the recommended dosage.

Yet US prescription drug spending

as a share of total national health expenditures

is in keeping with other countries.

So what's going on and why does it matter for public health?

To help us unpack the complicated picture,

we've brought together an esteemed panel.

And starting from my immediate right, I'll introduce them.

We have Aaron Kesselheim.

He's associate professor of medicine, Harvard Medical

School, Brigham and Women's Hospital,

and director of the program on Regulation, Therapeutics,

and Law.

To his right is Richard Frank.

He's professor of Health Economics

in the Department of Health Care Policy at Harvard Medical

School.

Next to him is Steven Pearson, president

of the Institute for Clinical and Economic Review.

And at the end is Leemore Dafny.

She's a professor of Business Administration at the Harvard

Business School.

Today's event is being presented jointly with Reuters.

And it is part of the Dr. Lawrence H and Roberta Cohn

forums.

We're pleased to welcome the Cohn family today.

Thank you.

We're streaming on the websites live now on The Forum

and on Reuters.

We're also streaming on Facebook and on Reuters TV.

The program will include a brief Q&A.

And so you could email questions to The Forum at Harvard--

no.

The Forum@hsph.harvard.edu.

And you can participate in a live chat that's happening

right now on The Forum website.

So prescription drug costs have entered the political arena.

In May, President Trump unveiled a blueprint

meant to address lowering drug prices.

Let's take a look at the announcement.

DONALD TRUMP: Today, my administration

is launching the most sweeping action in history

to lower the price of prescription drugs

for the American people.

We've wanted to be doing this, we've

been working on it right from day one.

It's been a complicated process but not too complicated.

And today, it's happening.

We will have tougher negotiation, more competition,

and much lower prices at the pharmacy counter.

And it'll start to take effect very soon.

My administration has already taken significant steps

to get drug prices under control.

We reformed the drug discount program for safety net

hospitals to save senior citizens

hundreds of millions of dollars on drugs this year alone.

We're also increasing competition and reducing

regulatory burdens, so drugs can be gotten to the market quicker

and cheaper.

We're very much eliminating the middle man,

the middle man became very, very rich.

Right?

Whoever those middle men were, and a lot of people never

even figured it out, they're rich.

CAROLINE HUMER: Well, despite this announcement,

A Politico Harvard Chan poll this summer

showed that just over 27% of adults

had heard or read about the blueprint.

And among those who were aware, about four in 10

think that it will lower prices.

And in 2018, recent reporting shows that drug prices

are still rising.

So as we will hear, the blueprint

is not the only plan in town.

Democratic proposals call for giving Medicare

the power to directly negotiate with drug manufacturers.

That would open the door to cheaper Canadian imports

as well.

And they want to impose fines on drug makers

for the kinds of dramatic price hikes that have made headlines.

So let's get into it a little bit and start with Aaron.

Can you describe the prescription price

setting landscape in the US?

AARON KESSELHEIM: Sure.

So first of all, it's a pleasure to be on this panel.

And thanks for inviting me to be a part of this.

So prescription drug costs in the United States

make up about a $450 billion market

and take up about 20% or so of health care dollars.

And some private payers are indicating

that they now account for about a quarter

of all their spending.

And prescription drug spending in general

is driven by brand name drug prices, which make up--

brand name drugs make up about 10% of prescriptions,

but 72%, 75% of prescription drug spending overall.

And the sort of fundamental reason

why brand name prescription drugs are so costly

is that the drugs are priced at whatever the market will bear.

That's the sort of general fundamental principle for drug

pricing in the United States.

And in fact, the market bears a substantial amount.

And that's because it's a very inefficient and ineffective

market.

And I just want to sort of focus on a couple of reasons

why that is.

So first of all, there is a disconnect,

a fundamental disconnect between the physicians

that are prescribing the drug and the patients that are then

taking and paying for the drug.

And oftentimes, physicians don't know what drugs costs.

And then many patients have prescription drug insurance

to cover the costs of their products.

So they only are exposed to a small amount

of the cost of the product.

And many patients then also therefore

don't know necessarily what the full costs of a drug is.

And then, of course, when you talk

about the insurance and the payer market

for prescription drugs, there is a range of different payers

that we use in the United States to pay for drugs.

There are government payers like Medicare and Medicaid.

And we have various laws in place

that restrict the ability of those kinds of payers

to negotiate with pharmaceutical manufacturers.

And then there are, of course, private payers as well.

And they try to negotiate individually

through systems of complex confidential rebates

and other mechanisms, and that is not necessarily

a very effective mechanism.

And so, you know, fundamentally what we have--

brand name prescription drugs are protected by patents,

they're monopoly markets, and we don't have an effective way

of negotiating on the other side of that in order

to provide a counterweight.

And so I think what we'll talk about a little bit today

are some of the mechanisms that we could use to better do that.

But the sort of minor changes that

are mentioned and by Trump and the blueprint

are not necessarily going to get at that fundamental issue

until we--

And we're going to need to take some much more substantial

steps because the outcome of all of this inefficiency

and these high prices is that patients

have trouble affording the essential medications

that they need.

And so price-related medication non-adherence,

when patients don't take the essential medications they're

prescribed, is way too prevalent in the United States.

It leads to worse patient outcomes.

People with diabetes are unable to afford the insulin

that they need.

Patients with cancer are unable to afford the cancer

drugs that they need, and that will help them.

And so, you know, I think that that

presents sort of an ethical imperative

to try to take care of this issue.

CAROLINE HUMER: Thanks, Aaron.

It does sound complicated.

Richard, you have talked about diagnosing the problem

of high drug prices.

What's your assessment of what's going on?

RICHARD FRANK: Well, like Aaron, competition actually

does a pretty good job at harnessing the prices

when it's there.

And the question is, why isn't it there more often?

You know, the place that it doesn't do well

is when people are almost completely

covered by their insurance.

They don't pay very much out of pocket.

And where there isn't much competition,

either due to a patent monopoly or due to some variety

of other either regulatory factors or market factors

that keep competitors off the market.

And so when you have people that are fully

insured facing a monopoly where they

don't have a choice, an alternative essentially,

you have a recipe for high prices

and rapidly growing prices.

The Medicare Part D program, which

is the place where everybody is focused on for negotiation,

is sort of a really interesting example of this.

It essentially consists of two pieces.

One piece is you have specialty pharmaceutical insurance

companies competing to cover people.

And they in turn negotiate with prescription drug makers

for prices.

And if they pay more for a drug, that

comes out of their pocket, that comes out of their bottom line.

There's a second part to Medicare Part

D, which is what people refer to as the reinsurance part.

And there, patients pay about 5% of the cost.

These prescription drug plans, these specialty insurers

pay about 15%, and the government picks up 80%.

So are very little on the hook for that extra cost

of the drug.

And therefore, in those circumstances,

the incentive to fight hard for good prices

is dramatically weakened.

And so again, what you see is very high prices

in that section of the benefit.

And in fact, the entire growth of the program--

well, not the entire growth.

Almost the entire growth of the program over the last,

say, eight or nine years, has been

due to the growth in that reinsurance

part of the program.

Where, in fact, the competition is most likely to break down.

And it actually turns out to be a relatively small number

of drugs that are generating all the costs.

In Medicare, 90% of the prescriptions are for generics.

And generic drugs continue to fall in price for the most

part, with some exceptions, like the one you noted.

But there's about probably 10, 20 drugs,

maybe 25 drugs that cost more than $1,000 a month.

And that's where the problem really is.

And so that has been the focus of a lot of policy attention.

CAROLINE HUMER: Thank you.

Steven, let's dig a little bit deeper and talk a little bit

about, you know, brand name drugs.

How they're priced here, how they're priced in Europe.

What's the difference there and what's going on?

STEVEN PEARSON: Sure.

There's a big difference.

I mean, when a new drug is approved by the FDA, not all

the time, but we often have the chance to celebrate science

and, you know, an achievement that

will really benefit patients.

And that does capture a fair amount of media.

But what's interesting is that every time that happens,

something else has occurred.

Either that day or in and around that time.

And that's a kind of uniquely-- in an economy,

a company gets to name its price.

And that price is the price that the government

will pay for what that company has developed

without any direct negotiation.

Now, to be fair, the prices are thought about for years

and then kind of a final phase happens just before the launch.

And companies do have to think about

the competitive landscape.

So you know, if they want a certain amount of market share,

just like any other kind of marketplace,

they have to think about how their price will compete

given its relative advantages for patients

versus another drug.

The reason that hasn't led to a lot of control

on costs, certainly compared to Europe,

is because drugs are not easy to walk away from.

It's not like a cell phone or a car where you can go next door

and get a different brand.

And it's essentially the same thing.

And you can make your own trade-offs.

Drugs really do have slightly different characteristics.

And so, we as patients and we as physicians,

we as health systems, want to make

a broad variety of the developed drugs available.

So that tilts the kind of the dynamics of the market,

if you will, on top of having a patent system that

at launch will give a company, again,

a certain number of years during which it may have the landscape

entirely to itself.

So think of name your price as a simple overly simplistic,

but that's kind of the way it happens in the US.

The reason that they don't charge $10 million

is because Congress would probably get a whiff of that

and want to have a special hearing.

And you know, the whole system might come crumbling down.

Europe does it differently.

And I'm using Europe very obviously stereotypically.

But it's every other developed country.

So you can start at the South Pole and go to the North Pole.

Many middle and developing countries

also have some system of doing three things.

And like any good slogan, it rhymes.

They aggregate the buying power.

They evaluate the clinical and cost effectiveness.

And they negotiate.

So they aggregate, evaluate, and negotiate.

Aggregation means that they pool, basically

either in a national health insurance system

or by cobbling together the existing private market in very

specific ways, to have basically all the weight of having all

the patients or all the members of a country

kind of have the weight of that in the negotiations.

So that you can say, well, if we pick your drug

or we do make your drug more available,

it's going to get a lot of uptake.

Whereas if we don't, you're really

going to hurt in this country.

So that lends to a different dynamic in negotiation.

They evaluate the evidence.

Every other developed country has a federal instituter agency

that takes a close look at the comparative clinical

effectiveness of drugs at or near the time of launch

to help inform that process of what comes

next, which is negotiation.

And negotiation looks very differently

in different countries.

It really does, they have different structures.

But ultimately, the key part about negotiation

is that these countries are willing to stick with it.

They're willing, in some cases, to say no.

If the price doesn't seem to mean

that it's a reasonable value for them and it's affordable,

they're willing to play hardball.

And you can have some very famous examples.

One going on right now is around cystic fibrosis drugs

in many different European countries.

There is a real roadblock going on between governments

and the manufacturer.

So they aggregate, they evaluate,

and they negotiate, and they mean the last phase

to have teeth.

And I think that's one of the biggest differences

that I see in how drugs are priced in the US

versus in Europe.

CAROLINE HUMER: Thanks.

Leemore, Richard spoke a little bit

before about how consumers in the government programs

are protected by this structure.

You have also researched the impact of rising drug

costs on consumers, and surprisingly

found that many consumers in commercial plans,

ones offered by employers or other institutions,

may not be feeling the hit of these higher drug

prices in the way that we think they are.

Can you tell us more about that?

LEEMORE DAFNY: Sure, absolutely.

First of all, thank you for having me here today.

And I'm going to echo some of the themes that have already

been mentioned.

But a very little known fact is that they share that consumers

are spending for their drugs today

is actually lower than it was over 10 years ago.

And in fact, I looked up the statistics this morning,

national health expenditures, and discovered

that the absolute dollar amount that we are spending out

of pocket for retail prescription drugs

has gone down.

OK?

So that is true in spite of the fact that prices are going up.

And I'm not just talking list prices,

I'm saying spending is in fact going up.

And I believe that this protection of sheltering

consumers, just as Richard mentioned,

sheltering consumers from the actual cost

of these medications is part of what is

driving the growth in prices.

And there are various mechanisms that pharmaceutical companies

can employ to shelter consumers.

Including co-payment coupons for the commercially insured,

patient assistance programs for Medicare enrollees.

And those are mechanisms that tamp down the demand

sensitivity to prices.

Now, that's not the only component.

Another component is then it disables

the ability of pharmaceutical benefit managers

to try to negotiate for better prices in exchange

for preferred tier placement on their formularies.

Because if I'm not paying much out of pocket because I have

a coupon I can use, then I don't really

care if it's a tier 4 drug.

And therefore, that manufacturer just

wants to make sure that the drug is on a formulary,

but is sort of indifferent to the pressure,

doesn't have pressure to keep the price low.

And so I'm currently trying to do some research

to try to quantify the effect of these programs

in driving prices up, but I believe it's significant.

There are two other factors that I'm

hoping to mention in addition.

One was echoed previously, which is there are some really high

priced drugs without strong therapeutic substitutes that

are driving high spending.

And in the past, we've benefited from generic entry

when we were talking about chemical compounds

bringing down the prices of drugs.

But now these drugs are primarily biologic compounds.

And we haven't seen the same entry

of biosimilars in the United States

or adoption of biosimilars, let alone any

of the willingness to take hard bargaining stances

as Steve Pearson has mentioned.

So that's, I think, another key driver

of what we're seeing today.

And last, and hopefully we'll be able to discuss it

in somewhat greater detail as the panel continues, but there

are a fair number of strategies that

the pharmaceutical manufacturers employ,

which FDA commissioner Scott Gottlieb called shenanigans.

These are attempts to shield their products

from competition.

And also to evergreen their products

and create new formulations, but at the same time

avoid competition from generics.

And all of these are really important factors

in causing higher spending, even if consumers are not

themselves shouldering out of pocket a greater

share of that spending.

CAROLINE HUMER: Thanks, Leemore.

We will get back to talking about those shenanigans

for sure.

So we've heard a lot about the drivers of drug prices.

And now we're going to hear from a patient.

This is Pam Holt. And this video comes from the US department

of Health and Human Services.

PAMELA HOLT: My name is Pamela Holt. I'm a retired teacher.

I have in this last year had to pay over

$10,000 in medical costs for my drug to keep me alive.

I was a newly retired principal at an elementary school

and feeling pretty good about retirement.

Just kind of out of the blue was diagnosed

with multiple myeloma.

I had one drug specifically that was very costly.

Without the drug I am on, my survival rate is much less.

I need the drug.

I thought I had a comfortable retirement being an educator

and having social security.

But it turned out that this drug was more than I

could handle on my income.

It became very costly for me to the point

where just recently I had to refinance my home.

It's impacted my life seriously.

I have eight grandchildren.

I really would like to spoil them and take them

places and do things with them.

I can't do that.

I would love to see action done that

would help generics to come on the market

because that would help me personally.

And I feel strongly that drug companies are just

gouging patients who are dying.

VOICEOVER: American patients first.

HHS.gov/drugpricing.

Produced by the US department of Health and Human Services

at taxpayer expense.

CAROLINE HUMER: OK.

Well, let's talk now about ways that we

can address these drug prices.

You know, what can be done, what is already being done.

I think a good place to start here

would be with that Trump blueprint

that we referenced at the beginning.

That was announced in July.

There's about six weeks until the midterm elections.

And wondering if anyone on our panel

might just address, you know, whether or not

anything has come from that or if we should be expecting

anything from it in the next six weeks that could,

you know, answer some of these issues

for people like Pam Holt. Anyone?

AARON KESSELHEIM: Well, so I'll start.

CAROLINE HUMER: Thanks, Aaron.

AARON KESSELHEIM: So I think, I mean,

again, I think we all support Pam Holt

and want to see her do the same sorts of--

and want to have the same kinds of goals

that she has in trying to get drug

prices to a reasonable level.

The blueprint itself had, you know, had a lot of ideas in it.

It had a lot of ideas at a very sort of high, vague level.

There weren't a lot of specifics about particular interventions.

There were a lot of questions that

were asked where it seemed like the government was just

trying to get information.

There were some good ideas and then

there were some ideas that are probably useless or bad ideas.

And so I don't necessarily think that this

is a strategy or a clear path forward

for trying to address these issues.

But I do want to point out one of the positive issues that

was mentioned in the blueprint and that was mentioned earlier

by Leemore is the idea of getting competition

onto the market at a reasonable time.

And the only kind of competition that

substantially and consistently lowers drug prices in the US

is competition from interchangeable generic drugs.

And so when there are very expensive,

you know, biologic molecules where

you don't have that same kind of interchangeable competition,

then you can get high prices extended out indefinitely.

And so to the extent that the blueprint talked about it

as an aspirational goal to try to get

more interchangeable competition on the market,

I think that was one of the positive ideas that

was in that document.

CAROLINE HUMER: OK.

And that competition, it sounds, Leemore,

like you're talking about some shenanigans that prevent that

from happening.

Maybe you could just share that with us.

LEEMORE DAFNY: Before I go to shenanigans,

though we love to talk about them, with good reason,

I just want to piggyback on something that Aaron just

mentioned, which is the potential

to see more competition in the biologic space.

And what actions the administration

could possibly take to promote that.

And he touched on this issue of interchangeability.

And that's really the engine of success for generic drugs

because you get a prescription from your physician,

you go to the pharmacy, the pharmacy

can automatically substituted it for a generic compound

and for any manufacturer of that compound.

The FDA has so far chosen to reject calling biosimilars

by the same non-proprietary name as the biologic reference

product.

And so that change in the naming guidance

would help with this interchangeability

that was referenced.

And the FDA also could release guidance

on what is going to count as interchangeable

and ideally not make it as onerous as they

have suggested in the past.

So there are actions that could be taken to foster greater

competition in that space.

There are also actions that the manufacturers themselves,

the shenanigans that we talked about,

employ in order to maximize profits.

And one of those that has gotten a lot of attention of late

is choosing to withhold samples of their products from, I

should say, manufacturers seeking to copy them.

And you can understand competitively

why they would want to do that.

But the rationale is that these manufacturers don't

have a proper prescription for having this medication

and it might fall into the wrong hands.

And then the manufacturer might be

responsible for anybody who's mishandled or misused

the drugs.

And there have been many, many statements

by public officials saying that the law was specifically

designed to enable manufacturers to try

to copy these medications.

And the pharmaceutical industry continues

to resist legislation that would explicitly

require the samples to be provided at market prices.

CAROLINE HUMER: Just to skip back

for a second to that interchangeability,

is there any indication that the FDA,

that the commissioner, Scott Gottlieb,

is leaning towards the idea of interchangeability

in the new policies coming this fall?

LEEMORE DAFNY: You want to take that?

RICHARD FRANK: Do you want me to take that?

CAROLINE HUMER: Sure.

RICHARD FRANK: OK.

This has been a debate that's been going on since 2010

within the administration.

The Affordable Care Act, within the Affordable Care

Act was all the authority you need for the FDA commissioner

to, one, define interchangeability

and set the guidance for doing that.

Provide proprietary names, and even more importantly,

set up a sort of rapid process for review.

And all of those have been very sluggish.

Moreover, on the payment side, what

you could imagine being done and was proposed

was to put all of these drugs under one price,

under one code.

And so therefore, if you have a cheap drug and a high drug,

you get a much better deal if you go for the biosimilar,

or the generic in this case.

That hasn't happened.

And that's also not so much an FDA problem

but the Center for Medicare and Medicaid problem.

But all of those things are within the authority

of the administration and would have a dramatic effect

on competition.

CAROLINE HUMER: So to look a little bit at competition.

One of the things that comes up a lot, Steve, for you, I think,

is where should these drugs be priced at in the first place.

And you know, what are they actually worth,

what is the value of them?

Can you maybe just talk a little bit

about the idea of an independent evaluation

and how that might help fix the problem in the US

with these prices?

STEVEN PEARSON: Sure.

Well, as we've all been talking about, and as you mentioned,

this is a complex system.

So there's no one silver bullet.

No matter what you think it might be,

it's going to have to be a real sustained thrust with lots

of different features having to do with competition

and other aspects as well.

So I mentioned the way that drugs are kind of-- new brand

drugs have been priced.

It's kind of what I hope will be viewed as old school

more rapidly than not, because a very common way

to think about how the price should

be aligned with the benefit to patients is to measure that.

I mean, we get a lot of that data

from the trials that are used to get FDA approval.

We find out whether the drugs extend the length of life

for patients and/or improve their quality of life.

Sometimes that's by having fewer side effects

or whatever it might be.

Now, you can kind of just do a Gestalt

and say, well, it seems a little bit better or a lot better.

But you can actually do cost effectiveness analysis,

which really tries to measure it in a quantified way, not

just in the short term but really over the long term.

So we capture the real long-term benefits

to patients and the real long-term possibilities

that, even if it's expensive upfront,

it might reduce hospitalizations or doctor's visits

or other things that will kind of balance that out.

So you wrap that all together and you

can scale a price at how much higher it should

be than our best current care, if something is better,

by how much better it is.

And you scale it to the wealth of the country.

So we would actually-- one of your questions

is, why are the price is high in the US?

We're a very wealthy country.

For a given gain in health, we would pay more in this country

than they would in a poor country.

That's kind of OK.

So it doesn't bother me to see lower prices in some countries.

It's basically their ability to pay, their willingness

to pay, given their other societal needs.

Well, we do have other societal needs, too.

We have education and defense and the environment.

So we can't spend everything on health.

So again, you scale up the price so

that you get a reasonable additional cost for an added

health gain.

And that's a really good place to start,

I think, in part because it sends the right signals

to manufacturers.

We want you to go out and hit a home run for patients.

We want you to demonstrate that it really

improves their quality of life or length of life.

We're going to handsomely reward you if you do.

But if you come to us with this much,

and it's smudgy around the borders,

and you haven't done good studies,

and we're still in a system where

you can name your own price, again, that should be obsolete.

The fact that you could charge us a lot more even though it's

just like this, and we don't have many options

to do something else.

So I'm hoping that we're moving.

And I think we are seeing some movement, not

at the federal government level yet necessarily,

but in the private system and some of the state

Medicaid programs, I think we're starting

to see some movement towards seeing pricing as a way

to reflect the added benefit to patients as a good anchor

from which to start.

LEEMORE DAFNY: And if I could just summarize what you said,

the manufacturers do think a lot about the prices that they set.

But the purchasers, they don't think very much

about the prices they're willing to pay.

STEVEN PEARSON: I would say that's because, even if they,

traditionally, if they said, I'd like to pay $100 for this,

but the company is charging me $200,

the time they put into figuring out that 100 wasn't worth too

much, because they're going to have to pay 200 anyway.

LEEMORE DAFNY: Mmm.

STEVEN PEARSON: That's part of the problem.

LEEMORE DAFNY: And the reason they're

going to have to is they're not willing to make trade-offs

and evaluate what's the value added of this medication,

and this is how much it's worth to us.

We don't see a variety of products on the market--

an older formulation of insulin, newer formulation

with different prices, and then choices

for physicians and their patients.

So the demand side is very inelastic.

So of course, they end up paying.

STEVEN PEARSON: That's true.

AARON KESSELHELM: And not only that--

I think it's more than they're not

willing to make those choices.

I think that sometimes they're not able to make those choices.

We have laws and rules about not excluding certain drugs

from formularies.

Various states have laws about coverage of certain drugs.

And when you have rules about the way

that Medicare and Medicaid is implemented

that forces insurers to cover all these products,

then yeah, they could say, great, I'd

love to pay only $100, but the manufacturer says,

well, the law says you have to cover it,

and we have a patent so we're the only manufacturer that's

making the product, and so we say it's $200,

and that's what you're going to pay us.

CAROLINE HUMER: And I think that one drug we could talk about

along those lines is Humira.

It's the biggest drug in the US.

Their global sales are $19 billion.

There is competition, more or less.

There are other drugs out there to treat the same things.

It's the biggest drug for government spending.

And I know, Richard, that you have looked a little bit

at the issues.

This is a drug that the price goes up

every year in the double digits.

It hasn't stopped.

That's driven it up to--

basically, I think it's over $10,000 now a year

for that drug.

And what are some of the ways that the government,

as such a big spender and big payer, can harness its power

or change the way its buying drugs like this

to reduce the cost?

RICHARD FRANK: Yeah.

So I think, going back to the beginning,

there are really a limited number of drugs out there

that are really high cost, that have little or no competition,

that you can focus on through negotiation.

The question is, how do you do that?

Because you have, in a sense, two problems.

You need to have the system set up that sort things

out when there's disagreement.

And you have to have some protection that you're not

going to drive the price so low that, in fact,

there won't be any incentive for innovation,

and there won't be an ability to make enough money to get

a reasonable return.

And so there have been several ideas put forth.

One of them has been binding arbitration.

And we use that for a lot of other necessary services

in this country.

Like when police and firemen have

a labor dispute over wages, they're not allowed to strike.

So what you do instead is you submit to binding arbitration.

And there are rules that define that.

And we do it in the most important products,

which is the NFL.

And how we sort things out that way there.

So that would be one way.

Another way would be to, in a sense,

have a methodology set out along the lines

that Steve might design to set a fallback price.

And if there isn't agreement, then there

would be some analysis done that would then

define a fallback price.

But that wouldn't be known until after the negotiations failed

so that everybody would have an incentive

to come together and negotiate a fair price.

AARON KESSELHELM: Does that seem possible, Steve?

Could we get to that?

STEVEN PEARSON: Anything's possible,

depending on how challenging the budget issues become

and how much political pressure is focused

on any one particular area.

There's a lot going on in Washington any day

of the week or month.

But prescription drugs are particularly

relevant because over 50% of Americans take them every day.

And it's something that touches our families both clinically

and their pocketbook.

The problem is also that we all want innovation.

We all want the next great CAR-T drug

that's going to take a pediatric cancer patient who

was going to die in six months and is giving them

two, three years more, maybe it's a cure.

I mean, these are things that don't happen

with every new drug, but we have to make sure

that we have the resources to handsomely

reward and incentivize those kinds of home runs

and not squander them where we fail to discriminate,

as I was talking about before.

So I do think--

one thing-- when you hear about Medicare negotiation, it does

actually sound easy on the surface,

but once you get even one layer down, it gets really tricky.

Does that mean that Medicare would

have one national formulary and kick one drug out of the market

entirely to get the best price on another one?

If so, if they've got that much power,

why wouldn't they have, as you said,

maybe run the risk of driving the price down too low?

Because there's always more money to save,

if you drive the price down lower,

and if you're the only game in town.

So we are uniquely American in all good and maybe questionable

ways, but the idea of a national formulary

is hotly debated, even in progressive circles.

So arbitration is an interesting alternative,

or other options in which we try to let the free market work.

But again, I've heard about it called baseball arbitration,

where the two sides come together

and the ultimate arbitrator can't split the difference.

They have to pick one offer or the other

at the end of the day.

And that means that everybody has

to be as reasonable as possible.

And more likely than not, in that situation,

I think the companies will really

refer to data on how well their drugs help patients.

They won't make vague claims about needing a high price

to sustain future innovation.

They'll really kind of get down to how well their drugs really

work.

And the payers will probably do something quite similar.

So it all depends on the budgetary--

you know, how many years before we go

broke in Medicare and other ways.

But with an aging baby boomer population,

with fantastic innovation in the pipeline, which

is without a doubt--

the genetic science is coming to fruition--

I think we're going to have to figure out

some new ways forward, because what we want

is a grand bargain.

We want a fair price, and we want that drug to be accessible

so Pamela Holt doesn't have to pay

$10,000 each year out of her own pocket for it.

And we're not there yet.

So I really hope we wake up in five years

and we've achieved, one way or the other, some kind

of grand bargain, because that's the way that's

going to help real patients.

CAROLINE HUMER: And so far, those kinds

of arrangements between payers and drug companies

have been very limited to a few drugs where it's well known

that the drugs are working well.

So there's quite a road ahead to that.

And in the meanwhile, it seems that the pharma companies

are doubling down even on their co-pay coupon policies

to try to make the drugs more affordable for patients.

And Leemore, I just wanted to hear a little bit more

about how those programs affect people's price sensitivity, how

it affects this pricing, and what could or should

change there as well.

LEEMORE DAFNY: Sure.

Well, I think that regulators need

to give further thought to the policies

vis-a-vis co-pay coupons and patient assistance

programs because having the manufacturers of medications,

who are responsible for setting the prices,

also be the ones who are issuing coupons

and/or making tax-deductible donations to foundations that

then turn around and help patients

bear their cost sharing component of the drugs

is like having a fox guard the henhouse.

So if these co-payment coupons are

banned for Medicare and Medicaid,

although they have low co-payments,

but Medicare enrollees-- and the reason

is they're viewed as kickbacks.

They're not banned for commercial enrollees.

And I personally was able to do a study on one particular kind

of coupon, which are coupons for branded molecules

when there are generic bioequivalents available.

And unsurprisingly, availability of the coupons

leads to increase in utilization of the branded drugs.

It doesn't actually increase total utilization

of the molecule or any evidence of improved adherence.

It does increase spending substantially.

That's just the tip of the iceberg.

That's just when you know there's an identical copy

of the drug available.

A bigger issue is when there are a variety of drugs

without perfect bioequivalents and the coupons

prevent us from really caring how much the drug is priced.

And some of these programs will pay all of your deductible.

And you probably heard some stories

about how some insurers are fighting back and saying,

you know what, if somebody else pays your deductible,

it's not going to count--

these co-pay accumulator programs--

it's not going to count toward your deductible, and partly

why should a patient who takes a drug that has a coupon not

have to foot her deductible when another patient who

has to have expensive treatments that don't have coupons does?

So there's a lot of-- there's inequity in that.

And just even thinking about this,

you can imagine that it's entirely broken.

So the one thing in the Trump pricing plan

that kind of surprised me was to see

mentioned that maybe these co-pay coupons

should be permitted for Medicare enrollees,

because that would very likely lead to more price

inflation and higher prices.

So I'm kind of puzzled by that one.

CAROLINE HUMER: And I guess one of the parts of this new co-pay

back and forth between the payer and the drug company

is the consumer in the middle.

So have you noticed that that has increased their exposure,

if suddenly the deductible is not

covered by the drug company?

It seems like one day, you're not paying anything,

and the next, you are.

LEEMORE DAFNY: Right.

I mean, certainly consumers-- it's

the coincidence of the deductibles

and the rising prices of drugs that

has got this topic in the news so much,

because as I said before, the stats

show that we aren't spending more out of pocket,

but it's very visible to us because we

have the deductibles.

So there is some pressure on the manufacturers.

And if the insurers implement these accumulator programs

where they don't allow the manufacturers to offset

the spending, then we get a little bit more demand

sensitivity.

But the consumers in the middle, let me just be clear,

that isn't really the optimal way to go.

We don't actually want chronically ill patients

to be like Pam Holt. We don't want

them to be any more disadvantaged than they already

are.

So ideally, we wouldn't have a one-size-fits-all policy.

We would have value-based co-payments,

and we'd have patients with chronic diseases

taking high value drugs at very low cost to them.

CAROLINE HUMER: Great.

Thanks.

Lisa, do you have any questions?

LISA MIROWITZ: Caroline, thanks.

Yes, we have a number of them coming in right now.

So let's start with this one from Jacob

who's with the Special Committee on Aging with US Senate.

Are we seeing the European Federal Institute's agencies

you mentioned take US prices into account

while evaluating cost effectiveness of a new drug?

Specifically for specialty medications,

but also in the entire space.

STEVEN PEARSON: I should probably take that on.

No.

Basically, when you do a cost effectiveness analysis,

you would want to take the costs in your own health care system.

Actually, even sometimes the drugs

would be compared to a different kind of best standard of care

in a different country.

It can differ from what you see in the US.

So they would not.

They're aware that our prices are, in general, higher,

but that doesn't factor into their own consideration.

A few countries do kind of a crosswalk

just to make sure how their prices ultimately

compare to a basket of other developed countries.

To my understanding, for a while the US

was part of that basket for some countries like Canada.

But because our prices have become so high,

they've tended to kick the US out of their comparator

because they don't want to falsely peg themselves

to a higher price.

So they tend to peg themselves to other countries

where the pricing is more in line with their own.

LISA MIROWITZ: Great.

Great.

Thank you.

We'll take some from online and then

we can check the studio audience here.

Let's see.

I guess this might be a question for Richard.

What are your thoughts on the six protected drug

classes in Part D?

Do you think these should be eliminated?

RICHARD FRANK: The answer is some.

The six protected classes in Part D

touch on HIV drugs, psychotropic drugs.

And the original idea behind them

is that they were, at that time, mostly branded,

and they were different enough from one another

in the responses of patients who were different enough

that you didn't know it till they had taken

the drug, that people were hesitant to allow

for aggressive formularies to be applied in those areas.

The world has changed since then.

For example, antidepressants are now mostly generic.

So there's-- you don't need to go one way or the other on that

one, because there's lots of competition there now.

But to the extent that you wanted

to try to drive things down a little bit further,

it's probably not necessary anymore

to have a protected class there.

For anti-psychotics, it may be a little bit different.

And so I think when you start getting there,

you're talking about extraordinarily vulnerable

populations where there's a tremendous amount of harm that

can be done from the wrong causes.

But in principle, you'd like to have as few of those

as you possibly could.

STEVEN PEARSON: Sometimes I just-- if you don't mind--

if you can imagine the analogy whereby

the government-- private insurance and Medicare is

required.

Well, maybe pick the Defense Department.

What if they were required to buy Lockheed's new airplane

at the price that the company decides,

no matter how much better it was than the current plane

that they're flying?

I mean, you can imagine we would just kind of furrow our brow

and say, now, why would any government want

to pay for airplanes that way?

Now, drugs, as you said, in vulnerable populations

are very different.

But the economics of creating a market in which you

have to cover every single drug and you can't, in a sense,

compete them head to head, and you

have to accept the prices as determined by the manufacturer,

it's a perfect storm for the rising prices

that we tend to see in the US.

RICHARD FRANK: An important thing now to note

is that there are other tools available.

So for example, you can have various utilization management

techniques-- prior authorizations,

et cetera-- applied to those.

And so that gives the plans a little bit

of negotiating power.

But Steve is largely right, and it's really

a matter of how bad are the harms that you can possibly do

from being overly restrictive.

LEEMORE DAFNY: And you really diminish access with those--

RICHARD FRANK: Right.

That's what I meant.

LEEMORE DAFNY: --those programs.

LISA MIROWITZ: Thank you.

OK.

This is from Sanjeev Sriram How do

we help more Americans understand that they

are paying twice for drugs--

once when their taxpayer dollars fund NIH-backed research

on for medications, and again when the drug corporations

demands exorbitant prices for those medications?

Drug corporations are spending more on marketing

than R&D. We've had a couple of questions about this,

so I know--

AARON KESSELHELM: So it is the case.

And we've done a lot of research in our group on this topic.

The key transformational drugs that emerge in the US

and around the world originate, in many cases,

from publicly-funded sources.

And there is a substantial amount of taxpayer investment

not only in the basic science and translational side,

but sometimes all the way up into the product development

part.

And we talked about the CAR-Ts earlier,

and those originated in publicly-funded science

as well.

And then what happens is ultimately,

when a product emerges and is synthesized,

then there's a patent on it.

And the pharmaceutical manufacturers

then control the patent.

And so they're able to control the prices

and control much of the revenue that then comes in.

And then the question asker is very

true in that a substantial amount of spending

on drugs in the United States comes

from Medicare and Medicaid, which are funded by government.

Those are government dollars as well.

And so it is the case that there is a substantial amount

of support for a great deal of innovation,

particularly the most important key innovation

that comes through.

and that, I think, is something that

does need to be better recognized and then

also potentially taken into account as we're talking

about what a fair price is.

LISA MIROWITZ: Great.

Thank you.

Do we have any questions from the audience?

Does anyone want to ask a question?

AUDIENCE: Hi my name is Naomi Sephi.

I'm a health policy student here at the Chan School.

My question is regarding the European market.

A lot of the pushback that we see

from pharmaceutical companies, as he said,

is that lowering drug prices will stifle innovation.

Do we see that happening in European markets?

Are we seeing these companies drown,

or are they able to remain sustainable and continue

innovating even when the government is

able to negotiate prices?

STEVEN PEARSON: Views on that are so across the board.

So you've heard, and I've heard, passionate, eloquent, informed

arguments that we overpay only because the Europeans underpay.

I've heard passionate, eloquent responses from economists

that--

now, why exactly, if they paid more,

would the companies decide to charge us less?

Why wouldn't they keep charging us the same price?

Isn't more profit what they're supposed to do?

And on the other hand, I do believe

that the ecosystem for innovation

is unparalleled in this country.

Your ability to raise venture capital,

to link up to the NIH science--

the best federal funding for basic science in the world--

and to get that into the market, into the clinical trials,

to work with academics--

if you talk to people in Europe they salivate at what we have.

So my hope is that there isn't a black and white ultimate answer

to this, where we can make this kind of unlimited claim

that we need the prices as they, or even more, to sustain

the innovation that we've got and that any percent

off the top will instantly cripple innovation and stifle

it.

I think there are ways to believe

that the companies have generally very high profit

margins.

There's a lot of risk, and a lot of reward,

but I think we have a very healthy

pharmaceutical industry.

And I really do believe that many of them

feel that, ultimately, their strategic interest is

in having some more kind of reliable and universal system

in which the prices are maintained and scaled

in a way that's more sustainable for the economies in which they

live.

Because otherwise, it's a race to the bottom or the top,

depending on how you look at it.

And so I think we have some recognition,

even among the manufacturing community,

that old school pricing and old schools

ways of justifying it just aren't

going to cut it going forward.

RICHARD FRANK: Can I add some color to that?

So I think one really important thing to add to this

is that a French company like Sanofi, they

make money selling here.

It's not like they only sell in France

and, therefore, the only thing that's going on

is the money they make in France to fund innovation.

They sell to the United States.

So to the extent that they make a lot of their money here

and a lot of their returns here, then

that affects the investment in those companies.

But it's not because the companies

are French or German or Swiss per se that their innovation

prospects are different.

AARON KESSELHELM: I also think we should think about what kind

of innovation we want.

And if their system is set up, as Steve talked about earlier--

if the system is set up in the United States that you can make

a lot of money with a little bit--

basically, putting a little bit of risk

to make a very small amount of change to a product,

then as a for-profit manufacturer,

that's where you're going to invest

the lion's share of your money.

And so I think we not only need to think about innovation

in general but we need to think about what kind of innovation

that we want to try to incentivize

and whether or not the system that we have currently set up

is incentivizing the right kind of innovation.

And unfortunately, I think, in many cases, it's not.

STEVEN PEARSON: Caroline, can I return to a question

that you asked earlier, just because I--

CAROLINE HUMER: Yes.

STEVEN PEARSON: Because I know, sometimes,

even after a full hour, it just seems so complicated, right?

And the Trump blueprint won't fix it,

and nothing else will fix it by itself.

So people sometimes can feel this sense

of just kind of hopelessness.

I want to mention briefly two experiments going

on in the Medicaid system and in the private market that

shows that I think people are willing to take some risks

and experiment.

One is the State of New York's Medicaid program.

They did pass a law that allows them to create a target

spending cap for their drugs within the Medicaid system

so that they can make sure they have

enough budget for other things.

If they're exceeding that spending,

they are now allowed to pick out drugs that are contributing

to that excess spend and to identify

a fair value-based price that they will negotiate down

to to get an even deeper discount than Medicaid

programs usually do.

And this is the first example of a public insurer in the United

States explicitly using cost effectiveness

to help it identify what is a fair price linked

to the ability to help patients, and how

do we create levers and carrots and sticks

and things to try to get us there.

Briefly, in the private market-- now, this

is very controversial.

It was just announced about four to six weeks ago.

CVS, which is obviously one of the big pharmacy benefit

managers, it's also a large self-insured employer.

And it decided to change its health insurance

for all of its employees, and there

are a couple of other companies doing it too,

where if after they negotiate to the best of their ability,

the drug's price for a new drug that comes out

doesn't get down to a fair value-based price as determined

by actually reports from ICER, my institute,

then it won't be covered.

It's not covered.

So this sounds like a European approach, right?

If it doesn't meet our cost effectiveness,

it's not going to be available.

And it's an early experiment to see what happens.

Do we get the prices down so that they

can keep the broad access, or do we

have drugs that are excluded?

And really, how do we manage that kind of tension

in the US system?

So I don't mean to overly stress that these are the right ways

to move forward, but it's a sign that the market and the states

feel the need to move forward.

And so I think whatever does happen at the federal level,

they may end up learning from these experiments.

And I think we'll see a lot of change

over the next year or two.

CAROLINE HUMER: Thanks, Steve.

That is an interesting program.

And they're grappling with it right now,

with the new drug that came out to treat migraine

that's quite expensive.

It doesn't meet their barrier, so we're watching that closely.

And so I think we'll wrap up now.

It's been a great hour spending it with you.

Before we go, I want to hear from everybody--

one minute or less--

your biggest concern and greatest hope moving forward.

Let's start with Leemore.

Are you ready?

LEEMORE DAFNY: Yep, sure.

Absolutely.

Biggest concern is those ultimately deciding

what to cover and at what price won't

be willing to make difficult trade-offs-- very

exciting to hear that the State of New York

is willing to give it a stab.

We tend to be more willing to try these things out

on our indigent populations.

I'd like to see some more stringent activity

on the commercial side, and what CVS is doing is promising.

Greatest hope is that we will engage consumers

more in selection of their health plans,

selection of prescription drug plans,

give them the option to select stricter formularies.

And if they do so, then I think we'll see a market response.

STEVEN PEARSON: So I live just outside of Washington, DC,

so I have lots of greatest fears.

In this domain, it's that--

and this is true in Europe, in Australia,

wherever else you go--

these issues around drug prices and access and costs

and patient care, they're not easy.

There's no system that feels like, oh, this is just

a smooth process, we have a decision making--

everybody's happy at the end of the day.

It requires the deepest effort of a society

to really grapple honestly with trade-offs and with limitations

around what we can spend and for whom.

And that's never easy.

And so my greatest fear is that, at this particular moment

in our political discourse, in our public discourse,

this will be really hard for us to handle.

But my greatest hope is actually born out

of some of our experience with public meetings where

we've seen patient groups really come to the table,

not just for their piece of the pie

but seeing the bigger picture.

And people starting to talk about this as an ongoing issue

that we as Americans need to sort out, and hopefully

in a way that will work for everybody, because cures

are coming.

You'll hear about them if you haven't already,

but we're having some fantastic drugs nearing approval

that will provide miraculous treatments for patients

with long-term diseases like sickle cell, hemophilia.

And if we don't figure this out, we're

going to have a head-on train crash between price, cost,

and access.

So we have to get these systems and our dialogue sorted out

because we're going to have a great problem to deal with,

which is cures for patients that we really want to help.

RICHARD FRANK: I guess my greatest fear

is that the politics of Citizens United,

which is money and politics, will

come to dominate where we land in our solutions,

because they often have in the past.

My greatest hope is that we, I think,

now have started to recognize how important competition

is if we're going to have a market-driven system,

and that we will aggressively sweep away the things that

get in the way of that right now, including especially

with the biologics side.

AARON KESSELHELM: So my greatest fear also

is that a lot of the things that we're talking about

may require some legislative changes, grappling

with patents, trying to evaluate the way

that the government buys drugs.

And that is problematic in the current--

to get sort of these kinds of major things

done in the current political environment,

particularly when there is an extremely well-funded lobbying

organization on the pharmaceutical industry

side that actively poses a lot of these kinds of changes.

But on the other hand, my greatest hope

is the kinds of efforts that you see at the state level

and that come out of patients, because there are surveys out

there that 75% of patients think that drug prices are

a big issue.

And if we really see patients step forward and make

their voices heard, I think that we can actually try

to push through the gridlock.

CAROLINE HUMER: Great.

Thank you.

Thanks, Aaron, Richard, Steven, Leemore, for joining us today.

Thank you to our audience and to our viewers.

I'd like to encourage you to tune into our next forum.

It is called Conflicts Over Science and Policy at the EPA--

Where Are We Headed?

That one will be October 19 from noon to 1:00 PM,

also at forumhsph.org.

Thanks for joining us today.

[APPLAUSE]

[MUSIC PLAYING]

For more infomation >> U.S. Drug Prices: Why Are They So High? - Duration: 1:04:18.

-------------------------------------------

GUNDO - Old Skhoon (Prod. ILYES) - Duration: 3:26.

For more infomation >> GUNDO - Old Skhoon (Prod. ILYES) - Duration: 3:26.

-------------------------------------------

Kirby: Right Back At Ya! Theme (PAL Version) - Donkey Konga - Duration: 1:02.

Heavy Heavy Heavy - that is name you should know!

Heavy Heavy Heavy - I am king of the show!

Do you want to fight me? That slaps me on the knee!

Heavy Heavy Heavy's the one!

I'm fighting right on the point!

I'm fighting right on the point!

I am not very smart but I'm pushing the cart!

You should run; I'm coming for you!

You should run; I'm coming for you! Hah!

THE ADMINISTRATOR: How can we help you, rapping monkey?

DK RAPPER: I need a CG to shoot that there Heavy!

THE ADMINISTRATOR: We are making just that at Mann Co. Industries!

DK RAPPER: (monkey noises)

Heavy Heavy Heavy - babies ahead!

Heavy Heavy Heavy - and you are dead!

I don't run out of Steam; I am credit to team!

Heavy!

Heavy! (Heavy!)

Heavy!

Heavy! (Heavy!)

Heavy!

Heavy! (Heavy!)

Heavy Heavy Heavy's the one!

Right back at ya!

Right back at ya! POW!

For more infomation >> Kirby: Right Back At Ya! Theme (PAL Version) - Donkey Konga - Duration: 1:02.

-------------------------------------------

Inktober| Lets Draw Jazza [Day 1] 2018 - Duration: 2:50.

hello everyone today I'm drawing Josiah Brooks his channel name for YouTube is

draw with jazza he's the first artist on YouTube to reach over 3 million

subscribers he has a lot of tutorials how to draw videos and he does all kinds

of art challenges I'll leave a link in the description of this video so you can

check his channel out the drawing that I'm doing here is with a Bic crystal

ultrafine point red pen it's a ballpoint pen to draw this I was doing a bit of my

scribble technique what I do is I kind of describe love to where where I think

things should go and then after I've got the shape of it done I go in and I work

in the form of it getting the eyes the nose and all that good to where the

shadings proper I do some cross hatching and I pay attention to the anatomy of

the face and I focus on trying to get all the shading done properly depending

on the direction of the light and the whole time I'm just constantly moving my

hand I tried to prevent myself from taking a break for any more than a

couple of seconds and this drawing took me about an hour to complete and the

last drawing I did today I was using a ballpoint pen as well but it was a

different kind of the big ball points I noticed that with this brand with the

crystal pen is it ain't goes down a little bit heavier then it doesn't with

the other pen and it can be an advantage or a disadvantage depending on what

you're drawing but for me it worked for this drawing because I had a lot more

darker areas such as the left side of the face and then when it came to the

shirt I just used the larger one-point-six ballpoint pen to shade

that in really fast because the challenge for this month is to only draw

with pens that are inked I'm not going to be using any colored pencils or

anything that's not that doesn't have ink in it but I had a lot of fun doing

this drawing and if you have any enjoying suggest

or anything good let me know in the comments down below let me know what you

think of this drawing that I did but for now thank you for watching I hope you

have a great day and as always don't forget to subscribe thank you

No comments:

Post a Comment